SYNOPSIS: The strange economics of economists.
Bob Barro doesn't
deserve a salary of $300,000 per year. But then, who does? The ability
to do innovative economic research is at least as rare as the ability to
sink a basketball through a hoop--and a lot rarer than many other abilities
that routinely command six- or even seven-figure salaries. So there is
nothing particularly outrageous in principle about the record-breaking
offer that has just induced the Harvard economist to move to Columbia University.
Still, the April
8 New York Times story that confirmed the rumors about Barro's deal
has caused quite a stir here in academe. Nobody, as far as I can tell,
begrudges his good fortune: Barro is, by anybody's standards, a first-rate
economist. But a description I once saw of Stephen Hawking's reputation
among physicists applies to Barro quite well: He is "esteemed but
not revered" by his colleagues. That is, there are a couple of dozen
other economists who can, with reasonable justification, regard themselves
as being in the same league. Are they all now going to be demanding comparable
paychecks?
Well, probably not. But
there is certainly the possibility of a pay and perks explosion among a
small circle of high-profile economists. Why--and what does it say about
economics as a profession?
The first thing you need to do is
drop any stereotype you may have about economists as a bunch of suit-wearing,
slogan-parroting guys divided into squabbling ideological factions. I have
never seen Barro in a suit (the photo in the Times was a revelation).
More important, nobody makes a career in academic economics by repeating
traditional slogans. "Free trade good, protectionism bad" may
get you a job at a think tank, but not at Harvard. Academic success depends
on a reputation for cutting-edge research--which typically means either
clever mathematical models or ingenious statistical exercises that redefine
some important issue or explode some piece of conventional wisdom. And
while there are, of course, factions and cliques within economics--don't
get me started--there is, in general, a surprising degree of agreement
about what constitutes good work. Mainly this is because leading university
departments value technical skill and originality rather than ideology
(in fact, the profession is startlingly apolitical, given how politics-driven
economics is outside the ivory tower).
Now it turns out that
the ability to write "home run" economics papers--yes, that's
the phrase everyone uses in hiring meetings--is a quite rare one. Anyone
who manages to do it two or three times becomes, in the eyes of the whole
profession, a "star"--again, that's the word people actually
use--and immediately becomes a very desirable commodity. A department with
five or six star faculty out of, say, 30 will be highly visible. It will
be the kind of department that can make a strong case to the university
administration that it should receive preferential financial treatment,
because it contributes to the prestige of the university as a whole, and
hence ultimately to the institution's ability to raise money. A department
without stars, no matter how excellent its teaching or worthy its long-run
contributions to human knowledge, will not be able to make that case. And
so any economist who has managed to establish himself (or, rarely, herself)
as a universally acknowledged star can routinely expect to receive offers
from many of the leading departments.
But not, until now, $300,000 offers.
What's going on? I think that a major part of the explanation lies in the
development of economic theory over the past couple of decades and a somewhat
dysfunctional response of the profession to those developments.
It is now becoming clear
in retrospect that the '70s and '80s were a sort of golden age for the
academic star system. Some big new ideas--"asymmetric information"
(the seller knows if a car is a lemon, the buyer does not), game theory,
"rational expectations" (the market is as smart as the economist
modeling it), monopolistic competition, etc.--opened up dramatically new
ways of thinking about a number of economic issues. (One of the truly ludicrous
things about Brian
Arthur's fantasy about how stodgy economists refused to listen
to his radical ideas is that it is set in an era that everyone knows was
in fact marked by a manic neophilia, a worship of the wild and crazy.)
And for a smart, teched-up guy it was a perfect environment for career
building: Just be the first person to work out how asymmetric information
could be applied to industrial organization, or game theory to international
trade theory, and--presto!--a star was born. It became not only possible
but common for a successful young economist to become famous within a few
years after graduate school, to become a full professor at a top school
in his late 20s or early 30s. (No sour grapes here: My own career followed
exactly that script.) And to this day, top departments regard instant stardom
as the normal career track for the kind of person they want to hire.
But something has gone wrong with
the star formation process. The people are as smart as ever, but the state
of economic theory has changed. The big, liberating ideas of the '70s and
'80s have been absorbed--we are liberated up to here--and now the problem
is one of application, of really careful work that helps us decide which
wild and crazy ideas actually make sense or fit the facts. A good barometer
of the change is the John Bates Clark Medal, which is given every two years
to an economist under 40 (which, incidentally, makes it harder to get than
the Nobel). From the '70s to the early '90s the Clark generally went to
home run hitting theorists, but the last couple have gone to empirical
labor economists whose reputations have been built not on a couple of thrilling
papers but from an accumulation of careful, data-intensive research. The
days of instant stardom, in other words, appear to be largely over.
And yet the demand for
stars continues unabated. Indeed, it has probably increased due both to
cultural contagion--this is the Age of Celebrity in all walks of life--and
to the heightened competition among universities for increasingly footloose
donor dollars. So what happens? Well, ambitious departments are in more
or less the same position as producers of action films who, having been
unable to find bankable new stars, are still bidding against each other
for the services of Arnold Schwarzenegger or Bruce Willis. If a young economist
should show even a simulacrum of old-fashioned star quality, he is likely
to be deluged with offers, but for the most part the race for academic
prestige has become a game of musical chairs in which everyone still wants
the same old enfants terribles, and there are not enough of them
to go around. (In my own field of international trade, the joke is that
there are only three people in the top 10.) Result: Juicy offers for a
handful of aging superstars.
It's not such a terrible thing. When
you consider how large a role economics plays in our national debate--and
how much of the public discussion of economics is dominated by cranks and
poseurs--seeing a serious economist like Barro get offered what is still,
by private sector standards, a fairly modest paycheck doesn't seem particularly
out of line. But I do worry that the Barro offer sends the wrong signals
to younger economists--that by telling them the profession still insists
on the appearance of superstardom, that it only values home runs when we
really ought to be looking for a solid series of base hits, it will encourage
what is already a disturbing propensity to favor attention-grabbing showmanship
at the expense of deeper, more time-consuming work.