Supply, Demand, and English Food
SYNOPSIS: Examines how the British discovered the world and all its bounty
We Americans like to boast about our economic turnaround in the
'90s, but you could argue that England--where I've spent the past few
weeks--is the real comeback story of the advanced world. When I
first started going there regularly in the early '80s, London was a
shabby and depressed city, and the country's old industrial regions
were a Full Monty-esque wasteland of closing factories and
unemployment lines. These days, however, London positively buzzes
with prosperity and with the multilingual chatter of thousands of
young Europeans-- French especially--who have crossed the Channel in
search of the jobs they can no longer find at home. How this
turnaround was achieved is a fascinating question; whether the new
Labour government can sustain it is another.
But I'm not going to try answering either question, because I've
been thinking about food. Marcel Proust I'm not (what the hell is a
madeleine, anyway?), but the change in English eating habits is
enough to get even an economist meditating on life, the universe, and
the nature of consumer society.
For someone who remembers the old days, the food is the most
startling thing about modern England. English food used to be
deservedly famous for its awfulness--greasy fish and chips,
gelatinous pork pies, and dishwater coffee. Now it is not only easy
to do much better, but traditionally terrible English meals have even
become hard to find. What happened?
Maybe the first question is how English cooking got to be so bad
in the first place. A good guess is that the country's early
industrialization and urbanization was the culprit. Millions of
people moved rapidly off the land and away from access to traditional
ingredients. Worse, they did so at a time when the technology of
urban food supply was still primitive: Victorian London already had
well over a million people, but most of its food came in by horse-
drawn barge. And so ordinary people, and even the middle classes,
were forced into a cuisine based on canned goods (mushy peas!),
preserved meats (hence those pies), and root vegetables that didn't
need refrigeration (e.g. potatoes, which explain the chips).
But why did the food stay so bad after refrigerated railroad cars
and ships, frozen foods (better than canned, anyway), and eventually
air-freight deliveries of fresh fish and vegetables had become
available? Now we're talking about economics--and about the limits
of conventional economic theory. For the answer is surely that by
the time it became possible for urban Britons to eat decently, they
no longer knew the difference. The appreciation of good food is,
quite literally, an acquired taste--but because your typical
Englishman, circa, say, 1975, had never had a really good meal, he
didn't demand one. And because consumers didn't demand good food,
they didn't get it. Even then there were surely some people who
would have liked better, just not enough to provide a critical mass.
And then things changed. Partly this may have been the result of
immigration. (Although earlier waves of immigrants simply adapted to
English standards--I remember visiting one fairly expensive London
Italian restaurant in 1983 that advised diners to call in advance if
they wanted their pasta freshly cooked.) Growing affluence and the
overseas vacations it made possible may have been more important--how
can you keep them eating bangers once they've had foie gras? But at
a certain point the process became self-reinforcing: Enough people
knew what good food tasted like that stores and restaurants began
providing it--and that allowed even more people to acquire civilized
taste buds.
So what does all this have to do with economics? Well, the whole
point of a market system is supposed to be that it serves consumers,
providing us with what we want and thereby maximizing our collective
welfare. But the history of English food suggests that even on so
basic a matter as eating, a free-market economy can get trapped for
an extended period in a bad equilibrium in which good things are not
demanded because they have never been supplied, and are not supplied
because not enough people demand them.
And conversely, a good equilibrium may unravel. Suppose a country
with fine food is invaded by purveyors of a cheap cuisine that caters
to cruder tastes. You may say that people have the right to eat what
they want, but by thinning the market for traditional fare, their
choices may make it harder to find--and thus harder to learn to
appreciate--and everyone may end up worse off. The English are often
amused by the hysteria of their nearest neighbors, who are terrified
by the spread of doughnuts at the expense of croissants. Great was
the mirth when the horrified French realized that McDonald's was the
official food of the World Cup. But France's concern is not entirely
silly. (Silly, yes, but not entirely so.)
Compared with ethnic cleansing in Kosovo and the plunging yen,
such issues are small potatoes. But they do provide, well, frites
for thought.